Difference in Kiyum between Gittin and Monetary Contracts - Part 3 of a 5 Part Series
TALMUDIC METHODOLOGY
By Rav Moshe Taragin
*********************************************************
This weeks shiurim are dedicated by Abe Mezrich
*********************************************************
Shiur #04:
Difference in Kiyum between Gittin and Monetary Contracts
Part 3 of a 5 Part Series
In the previous two shiurim, we
analyzed the machloket between R. Eliezer and R. Meir as a debate about
the nature of eidei kiyum. R. Eliezer requires eidei
mesira so that actual witnesses attend the delivery of the get and
provide the necessary kiyum. R. Meir, in contrast, does not require
actual witnesses for the kiyum, accepting a signed document (eidei
chatima) in place of kiyum; either a signed document indicates
delivery (anan sahadi) or it actually testifies to the delivery
(R. Chaim's claim). According to the Rif's view, even R. Eilezer allowed an
eidei chatima-only option, presumably concurring that kiyum
can be supplied even without actual witnesses attending.
This logic, explaining R. Eliezers
requirement of eidei mesira as functioning as eidei
kiyum, may have led to an interesting compromise. Most Amoraim (based
on Rav's position stated in Gittin 66b) accepted R. Eliezer's requirement
of eidei mesira for a get but allowed monetary contracts to
be processed without eidei mesira. The simplest way to understand
this compromise is to view the ENTIRE REQUIREMENT of eidei mesira
as based upon the need for kiyum. If this is true, Rav claimed that
gittin, as an example of a davar she-be-erva, require
eidei kiyum or eidei mesira, while monetary contracts,
which do not typically require eidei kiyum, do not require
eidei mesira. Rav effectively rejected Rebbi Meir's allowance of a
signed document in place of eidei kiyum.
However, kiyum is only necessary for a get and not for
monetary activities. Hence eidei
mesira are only necessary for a get!
In fact, Rav's compromise is so
self-evident that it challenges us to better understand R. Eliezer's position.
Rav's distinction is so compelling that it raises a pressing question: If the
entire eidei mesira requirement stems from the need for kiyum,
why did R. Eliezer require eidei mesira for monetary shetarot,
which dont typically require kiyum? Two different approaches may solve
this riddle and explain R. Eliezer's demand for kiyum or eidei
mesira EVEN for monetary contracts.
First, he may have minimized the gap
between monetary transactions and erva transformations. We typically
assume that these are fundamentally different; the former may be performed in
private and witnesses are only necessary if and when contentious litigation
emerges. As the gemara in Kiddushin (65b) asserts dismissively, in
monetary transactions, lo ivrei sahadi ela le-shakrei, witnesses
are only necessary for liars (and not for the actual execution of the
transaction). Erva transformations, in contrast, are more FORMAL and more
CEREMONIOUS and require the presence of eidei kiyum to lend them
credibility and, ultimately, effectiveness. If this is true, R. Eliezer's
requirement of eidei mesira for kiyum purposes in
monetary shetarot is indeed difficult to understand.
However, the gemara in
Kiddushin (at least according to the simple reading and the one repeatedly
endorsed by the Ketzot Ha-choshen) presents a very different picture
about the difference between erva and monetary transactions. Firstly, the
entire NEED for two eidei kiyum in cases of kiddushin and
gittin is derived from a gezeira shava based upon the word davar
appearing in the discussion of monetary transactions AS WELL AS within the
discussion of erva. Second, the gemara itself questions why
monetary transactions do not require eidei kiyum and provides what
appears to be a technical answer every monetary transaction contains an
INHERENT form of kiyum known as hoda'at ba'al din. In
monetary affairs, a self-incriminating confession is treated as actual
testimony. Logically then, any monetary transaction affected without argument
includes the confession of the two participants. Since this confession would be
acceptable in court, no ACTUAL eidim are necessary. Confessions are only halakhically
acceptable, however, if they self-incriminate WITHOUT negatively affecting
others (chav le-achrini). In erva situations, these confessions
are unacceptable, since they negatively affect others; the outcome of
kiddushin prevents others from marrying this woman and the outcome of
geirushin prevents a kohen form marrying this newly developed
gerusha. Thus, the inherent hoda'at ba'al din in
unacceptable and actual eidim are required for eidei kiyum
purposes. In monetary situations the inherent assumed confession plays the role
of eidei kiyum.
This gemara effectively portrays
monetary and erva events in very similar terms. They each REQUIRE
kiyum, but monetary transactions enjoy built-in kiyum in the form of
hodaat baal din. Since erva does not, we must demand actual
eidim. If this reading is accurate, it is entirely conceivable to require
eidei kiyum for monetary transactions in which the built-in
confession is not admissible.
Perhaps this is how R. Eliezer views the
case of shetar. Unlike typical monetary transactions, the issuance of a
shetar is a PUBLIC event with very PUBLIC ramifications. For example, the
issue of a shetar for a loan may ultimately lead to appropriation of
lands from those who purchased from the debtor. The very presence of a shetar
TRANSFORMS the monetary event into a PUBLIC or SHARED event. Perhaps R. Eliezer
argues that even though a shetar does not always NEGATIVELY IMPACT third
parties, it DOES create a public nature to the transaction, rendering the
hoda'at ba'al din of the two litigants unacceptable. At this
stage, the confession is not admissible, and ACTUAL eidei kiyum in the
form of eidei mesira are necessary. Though this is an unconventional
reading of the eidei kiyum requirement, it is certainly the more literal
reading of Kiddushin, and one which R. Eliezer may have adopted, in
requiring eidei mesira as eidei kiyum for a shetar.
Alternatively, R. Eliezers opinion may
have been premised upon a different notion. Perhaps he required eidei kiyum
for monetary contracts as an EXCEPTIONAL situation. In fact, there may be
precedent for exceptions in which a monetary case requires eidei kiyum,
as in a case of erva. The gemara in Bava Batra (40a)
asserts that kinyan chalipin must be performed in the presence of two
eidim. Rabbenu Tam (both in his comments to that gemara and to the
gemara in Kiddushin) flatly rejects this notion, since monetary
transactions cannot possibly require kiyum. However, the Ra'avad (in his
comments to Bava Batra quoted by the Shitta Mekubezet)
takes the gemara at face value. Chalipin is unique in that it
effects both land and metaltilin transactions; typically, acts of
kinyan that affect one cannot affect the other, since the terms of ownership
are so different. Pulling an animal displays new ownership but is obviously
irrelevant to land; building a fence displays ownership of land but has no
impact upon an animal. Chalipin is a kinyan without any meaningful
act. Transferring a handkerchief (and then retrieving it) hardly demonstrates
ownership!
R. Chaim famously elaborated upon
chalipin (based largely upon this gemara and the Ra'avad's position),
claiming that it merely signifies COMMON AGREEMENT (gemirat da'at) and is
an arbitrary method of signifying that agreement. Ultimately the AGREEMENT
itself transfers the item. Ironically, it is the lack of demonstrative nature of
chalipin that grants it such versatility. It is precisely for this reason
that chalipin is so versatile. Land-actions are irrelevant to portable
items. A kinyan based on common agreement can work on any item.
However, since chalipin is a
kinyan da'at (an act merely demonstrating agreement), presumably a HIGHER
level of da'at is necessary. Regular kinyanim, which do
demonstrate new ownership, require a base level of da'at, since the
kinyan is primarily affected through the demonstrative action, but the pure
kinyan da'at of chalipin requires a more halakhically
significant level of da'at.
One consequence of this required higher
level might be the need for eidei kiyum. Perhaps the function of eidei
kiyum is to ensure the seriousness of the parties. Monetary transactions
generally do not require this attendance, while erva transformations do.
Chalipin is unique in requiring eidei kiyum because although it is
a monetary process, it requires levels of da'at equivalent to erva
events.
Using chalipin as a precedent may
help explain R. Eliezer's demand for eidei mesira EVEN in the context of
monetary shetarot. As we noted above, logically, Rav makes a compelling
point: if the entire eidei mesira requirement is meant to provide
eidei kiyum, why should monetary shetarot require eidei mesira,
which are only required for erva contracts? Perhaps R. Eliezer likened
the process of a shetar to chalipin. Why should the delivery of a
shetar successfully transfer a parcel of land? Perhaps it merely
demonstrates common agreement, which affects the land transfer. If shetar
is viewed this way, that it works by signifying common agreement, it may indeed
require the higher level of da'at required by some for chalipin
and it may thus require attending eidei kiyum to ensure that da'at.
Therefore, Rebbi Eliezer required eidei kiyum or eidei mesira even
for monetary shetarot.